Amit
Bhaduri is a distinguished economic theorist. He has been a consistent critic
of mainstream neoclassical economic theory and the corporate-led growth
strategies that have emerged in India and other developing countries in the
wake of globalisation. He has been articulating alternative development
strategies that seek to mobilise the strengths and energies of the poor masses
who are currently disenfranchised and excluded from the growth process. His
books include Development With Dignity (2005), and The
Face You Were Afraid To See (2009). He is currently an internationally
selected professor at Pavia University, Italy, and a visiting professor at the
Council for Social Development, New Delhi.
Bhaduri’s
technical work has focused on distribution of work, growth and employment
generation in the Indian economy. He has also studied agricultural backwardness
under ‘semi-feudalism’. In this interview, he criticises India’s current model
of economic growth, and points to the areas overlooked by the myopic economic
orthodoxy.
Neeta
Deshpande: What are your views on Indian economic policies in recent times?
Amit
Bhaduri: What
is quite fantastic is the convergence of views across political parties in
India about economic policy. Whether the CPM [Communist Party of India
(Marxist)] or the BJP [Bharatiya Janata Party], when they are in power, they
all follow the same policy. There are two points to understand here.
First,
why did all parties come to the same conclusion? It’s because they all believe
that the investment climate in the country has to be maintained. During the
Nehru period, the Indira Gandhi period, and roughly up to V P Singh’s prime
ministership, the state was responsible for economic policy and its
consequences. Now, it is the private sector. This change was brought about by
creating an investment climate for corporations. Now in a country where there
are so many poor people with little purchasing power, without roads and
electricity, the only way to maintain the investment climate is through a
massive transfer of natural resources at cheaper prices. Water, electricity,
land and minerals are given away to corporations. This has now become the name
of the game.
The
second aspect is that the government is crippled because it withdraws from all
profitable activities. Activities for the social good like basic education,
healthcare, water and public utilities are privatised and converted into
profitable activities. This to a large extent is the common policy. It is
achieved by not allowing the government to have an active fiscal policy, or
active budgets. However, there is nothing in economics or the empirical data
that shows that a higher or lower budget deficit increases or decreases the
inflation rate. Nothing at all.
Along
with an investment climate, a climate of opinion that the fiscal deficit has to
be kept down is simultaneously created. This entails that the government cannot
spend sufficiently on education or employment guarantee. Also, these activities
are implemented through the government instead of decentralising them, so that
they can be stopped or diluted at convenient times.
These
are the two main planks on which almost every political party agrees. The 2003
Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act which says that it is the
government’s responsibility not to increase deficit, is supported by every
party. But it is not the government’s responsibility to see that the citizens
of this country have enough food to eat.
Is
there an either-or choice between the state and the market in terms of economic
policy?
No,
there isn’t an either-or choice. I want to make two points here, one about a
change that has taken place, and the other about what we should all fight for.
The
change that has taken place is that there is a third force which has become far
more important. These are the resistance movements by civil society against development
projects, which force the government and corporations to recognise that when
people resist unjust policies, they cannot be pushed beyond a point.
If
you think of India since independence, it was believed that the country had to
work as a unitary state: a Congress government in the centre and Congress
governments in the states, with maybe one or two exceptions. However, the
legitimacy of the states is recognised today. Whether for good or bad, now we
recognise the rights of the states in the federal structure.
Similarly,
I hope that a historical process will take place to decentralise power to the
Panchayats. This is a force which is neither the market nor the state. It would
redefine the state and its meaning. The only way forward to change the current
scenario of pro-corporate development, of the central state being an agent of
the corporations, is through decentralisation.
Also,
something very peculiar has happened in Indian politics. Owing to coalition
politics, state powers have come into play. Now the states have a vested
interest. You can be a very small party but can influence politics. So our
federalism has become stronger. This will happen even more if we recognise the
power of the Panchayats. If they are allowed to do things locally independent
of the centre and states, there can be much higher growth in local areas where
the Panchayats work better.
What
are your views on the high growth of the Indian economy and how it impacts
ordinary people?
Everybody
now recognises that high growth does not impact ordinary people’s lives well.
The government believed that high growth will help legitimise its policies,
even though it meant taking away the land and livelihoods of people. This has
not happened partly because the growth has trickled down so little that it has
not been a legitimising process at all in a democracy. When you talk to people
who are not part of the English speaking middle class, they don’t give a damn.
Talk to an autorickshaw driver or a farmer. They are not worried about whether
the growth [rate] is 7% or 8%. They are not worried about whether there is a
budget deficit or not. It is true that they might be worried about inflation.
But nobody has shown that there is a very clear connection or any connection at
all between budget deficit and inflation.
So
the economic debate is in what I call a stratosphere; it simply does not
interest ordinary people. What interests ordinary people is not growth, but
whether they get food, health and education.
Look
at the human development index – India’s rank is among the lowest. The dramatic
statement that there are two Indias is not true. There are no two Indias. There
is a small minority of people and corporations who are making money in the name
of growth, and the rest are usually indifferent to what is happening until it
affects their lives. And now this growth process for maintaining the private
investment climate requires that natural resources are transferred to
corporations, which has begun to have a direct impact on people’s lives. That’s
why there is so much resistance all around. People resist corruption that
happens in the name of development, they resist the taking away of land in the
name of development, they resist when this land is given away for real estate
in which only the upper-middle class can invest. It is this kind of resistance
which will define the other politics.
Why
doesn’t growth trickle down to the poor?
It is
not strictly true that growth does not trickle down at all. If you look at the
Indian data, there is enormous concentration of the benefits of growth at the
top. These people have made money because they got access to natural resources
at cheap prices. To a large extent, it is probably true that the upper-middle
class and the middle class have not lost out that much. Another 30-40% have
more or less maintained their position.
But
it is the lowest group which has paid the price for high growth. They have lost
their land, rivers and mountains in the name of growth. Even if there has been
a trickling down, the gap between the rich and poor has increased. Every study
shows this. Even the Planning Commission and [its Deputy Chairman] Montek Singh
Ahluwalia wouldn’t disagree. There are certain statistics which are robust. You
can discuss, for example, whether India has 33% or 40% poverty. You can play
the numbers game. But certain statistics are robust – India is growing much
faster now. Similarly, as a statistical fact, it remains that there has been a
huge increase in the disparity in people’s incomes.
When
inequality of this kind increases so rapidly, people who are rich and gaining
enormously buy goods which only the national and international corporations can
produce. Whether it is fancy jeans or a fancy car, you cannot produce these in
the villages. So you are continuously throwing people out, not only as
consumers because their purchasing power is not increasing, but also as
producers. After all, who can go to a mall? What percentage? We talk so much
about retail trade – but who will buy these goods? Those below the middle class
cannot buy them. This is the rule of the market.
When
you build an air-conditioned mall, you cannot use traditional skills, with the
result that a majority of Indians are ruled out of the growth process. This is
where Indian growth is crooked because it requires growing inequality to
sustain the malls, real estate businesses, etc. Also, for corporations to grow,
natural resources like land, water and minerals have to be transferred to them.
So there is a vicious circle in which greater inequality leads to greater
growth and vice versa.
What
are your views on the notion of a poverty line?
Well,
frankly, it’s a fool’s game. There are many reasons why it’s a fool’s game.
First, someone who earns just one rupee less is poor, someone who earns just
one rupee more is not poor. There is no notion of how far a person is from the
poverty line. So the entire concept is quite flawed, except when it is used in
a biological sense; that is, if a [range] in calorie consumption determines
whether a person is considered malnourished or not. But the poverty line as it
is used by the planning commission, economists and statisticians is really a
stupid game to play.
Second,
if you study it in detail, it depends on so many assumptions and the way the
data is collected, that actually you can change it almost any which way you
like. It is almost like the notion of democracy, growth, development, or any of
these abstract concepts. You define what poverty is, and then you say that
poverty is going up or down. I am of the view that the less time you spend on
this, the more time you will have for doing genuine things like allowing the
poor to participate through decentralisation, making use of their production,
seeing that urbanisation is not of such a nature that more and more water has
to be diverted from irrigation to cities. If attention is paid to such
fundamental issues, things will take care of themselves.
There
is no way to make a dent in poverty in a country like India without
sufficiently high employment growth at the bottom. And India’s performance in
this regard has been dismal. During the period of 8% growth, employment has not
grown at more than 1%. It grew even faster during the Nehru period, when growth
was less than 4%, but employment grew at 2%. The whole middle class was created
in this period. Today you have much higher growth, every worker produces much
more, but people are not being employed. In the private corporate sector,
employment has more or less remained the same. In a certain way, if the growth
does not have sufficient employment content, it is not development in a purely
operational sense.
It
is argued that without a poverty line, without a targeted public distribution
system (PDS) and welfare schemes, there is a lot of inefficiency and wastage of
resources and funds. What do you think?
What
do you think about the rotting food grains that you see when you try to
[reserve] them only for the poor? There is only one way to improve efficiency
in India, given the corruption and the nature of our political class. Those who
benefit should pay. If the corporations benefit, they should pay much more for
development, instead of talking vaguely about corporate social responsibility
and so on.
But
the basic way forward in the interests of the poor is not to leave things to
the corporations, but decentralise. Let those who benefit from the local health
centre run it.
What
are your thoughts on the current inflationary trend?
With so
many people who are at starvation or near starvation levels, an increase in
food prices is extremely critical in a sense in which it is not – leave alone
advanced capitalist countries – even in countries like China or Thailand. If a
construction labourer is consuming 1900 calories and food prices go up a little
bit and he can only consume 1700, his life is shortened by about 10-15 years
immediately, if the situation persists for one or two years. In this sense, in
human terms, India is extremely vulnerable to inflation. That is why,
traditionally, inflation in India has been a highly explosive political issue.
It
is when you make elections so expensive, and everybody agrees on the same
economic policies across parties, that the state loses touch with people, and
is no longer sensitive to how they are affected by issues like inflation.
Double-digit inflation would not have been possible thirty years ago. The
government would have immediately tried to do something about it. But today, we
have created a democracy which is insulated from such issues. The more the
state is insulated, the better it is rated by credit-rating agencies. This is
what inflation is all about.
The
government should have been far more sensitive to inflation. By now any
civilised government would have made policies to decentralise food
distribution. The government should provide capital to people to build their
own warehouses. At least some experiments should be started in this direction.
There is no other way. That will take the teeth out of inflation.
How
vulnerable is India to hot money?
India
is very vulnerable to hot money in two ways. One way is direct, like the recent
exchange rate going down and so on. Money can go out at any time.
But
at another level, the influence of hot money is also very important because it
paralyses the government much more than a coalition government. Earlier, India
used to have a foreign exchange crisis. Now it does not, but the government has
to attune policies to what hot money will not object to. For example, certain
kinds of hot money will certainly object to a large employment-guarantee
scheme. So the government is paralysed from doing almost anything pro-poor. The
influx of hot money will depend on whether investors think the country is a
good destination to keep money in or not. But who will give this chit?
Originally, it used to be the IMF [the International Monetary Fund] and the
World Bank, now it is Standard and Poor’s [a major US credit-rating agency]. If
they say your democracy is good, your democracy is good. If they say your
democracy is bad, it’s bad. Till now, our development or economic policies were
being evaluated. Now, they literally say that this Prime Minister should be
replaced by an elected one who can be more decisive. So whether our democracy
is good or bad is also rated by the credit-rating agencies.
No comments:
Post a Comment